Taxation
Comptroller of the Treasury of Maryland v. Wynne
The statesâ power to tax, the Supreme Court has long held, is restricted by the dormant commerce clause.1×1. See, e.g., Case of the State Freight Tax, 82 U.S. (15 Wall.) 232, 279â80 (1873). As a part of the Commerce Clauseâs silent command that the states abstain from discriminating against interstate commerce, state taxes on interstate activity must be âfairly apportionedâ2×2. Complete Auto Transit, Inc. v. Brady, 430 U.S. 274, 279 (1977). â that is, when more than one state could plausibly tax the same income, each state may tax only its fair share of that income. A long line of cases has imposed this fair apportionment requirement on statesâ taxes on multistate businesses.3×3. See Bradley W. Joondeph, The Meaning of Fair Apportionment and the Prohibition on Extraterritorial State Taxation, 71 Fordham L. Rev. 149, 153â54, 153 n.21 (2002). Last Term, in Comptroller of the Treasury of Maryland v. Wynne,4×4. 135 S. Ct. 1787 (2015). the Court for the first time held that a stateâs tax on personal income was subject to the restrictions of the dormant commerce clause5×5. See id. at 1796â98. : the Court invalidated Marylandâs personal income tax scheme after determining that it inherently burdened the earnings of individuals who resided in one state but worked in another.6×6. See id. at 1803â04. In deciding the case on the ground that Marylandâs income tax was inherently discriminatory, the Court avoided directly addressing an additional part of the fair apportionment inquiry. The Court thus left open the following question: when a resident earns income out of state, how much of that income can her state of residence tax (and how much must it apportion to the state where she earned the income)? The Courtâs dicta indicated that the answer to that question might be very different in the personal income tax realm than it is with regard to corporate income taxes, creating uncertainty about what states must do to âfairly apportionâ personal income.
The Maryland personal income tax scheme invalidated in Wynne consisted of three parts, all of which were collected by the state of Maryland: a standard graduated âstateâ tax, a âcountyâ tax, and a âspecial nonresidentâ tax.7×7. Md. State Comptroller of the Treasury v. Wynne, 64 A.3d 453, 457â58 (Md. 2013). The confusingly named âcountyâ tax went to the state too; it was so called because its rate depended on which county the taxpayer lived in. Id. at 458. This scheme created three categories of taxpayers. (1)Â Maryland residents who earned all their income in-state paid the state and county taxes. (2)Â Maryland residents who earned some income out of state paid the state tax and the county tax on all their income, but then got a credit from Maryland â for the state tax only â for income taxes paid to other states. (3)Â Nonresidents who earned some income in Maryland paid the state tax and the special nonresident tax on that income.8×8. Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1792.
The dispute in Wynne arose when Maryland, in accordance with its tax code, refused to give a resident couple a credit against their county tax for income taxes they had paid to other states.9×9. Id. at 1793. Brian and Karen Wynne had earned income in thirty-nine states as a result of Brianâs partial ownership of an S corporation, a structure in which income passes through the corporate entity, untaxed, directly to its owners.10×10. See Wynne, 64 A.3d at 459â60. The Maryland Comptrollerâs Office determined that the Wynnes could not take a credit on the county tax for the taxes they paid to other states, and so ordered the Wynnes to pay additional taxes.11×11. See Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1793. The Wynnes argued that Marylandâs failure to provide a credit for income earned out of state violated the dormant commerce clause.12×12. Wynne, 64 A.3d at 460. The Maryland Tax Court rejected their argument, but the Maryland Circuit Court agreed with the Wynnes.13×13. Id.
The Maryland Court of Appeals (the stateâs high court) affirmed the circuit courtâs decision, holding in favor of the Wynnes.14×14. Id. at 471. After explaining that Marylandâs failure to provide a credit on the county income tax implicated the dormant commerce clause,15×15. The court determined that the tax disincentivized Maryland residents from generating income in other states, potentially âaffect[ing] the interstate market for capital and business investment.â Id. at 463. the court applied the Supreme Courtâs four-part test for ensuring state taxes pass dormant commerce clause muster.16×16. Id. A tax satisfies this test if it â(1) applies to an activity with a substantial nexus with the taxing state; (2) is fairly apportioned; (3) is not discriminatory towards interstate or foreign commerce; and (4) is fairly related to the services provided by the State.â17×17. Id. (citing Complete Auto Transit, Inc. v. Brady, 430 U.S. 274, 279 (1977)). The court first determined that the tax scheme was not âfairly apportionedâ because it failed both of the Supreme Courtâs fair apportionment requirements18×18. See id. at 463â68. : it was neither âinternally consistentâ (if every state imposed an identical tax scheme, interstate commerce âwould . . . be disadvantaged compared to intrastate commerceâ)19×19. Id. at 464. Although this âinternally inconsistentâ inquiry sounds a lot like part three of the four-part test â which asks whether the tax scheme discriminates against interstate commerce â courts treat them as distinct analyses. nor âexternally consistentâ (individualsâ tax liabilities did not âreasonably reflectâ whether income was derived from out-of-state sources).20×20. Id. at 467. The tax scheme also, the court held, discriminated against interstate commerce.21×21. Id. at 468â70. The court determined that the Maryland county tax, plus the tax levied by the state where income is earned, plus Marylandâs failure to credit the out-of-state taxes, âcreate[d] the discrimination.â Id. at 469. Thus the tax violated the dormant commerce clause.22×22. Id. at 470.
The Supreme Court affirmed the judgment of the Maryland Court of Appeals.23×23. Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1807. Justice Alito, writing on behalf of a five-Justice majority,24×24. Justice Alito was joined by Chief Justice Roberts and Justices Kennedy, Breyer, and Sotomayor. began by defending the âdeep rootsâ of dormant commerce clause doctrine,25×25. Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1794. explaining that its prohibition on state laws that discriminate against interstate commerce prevents âeconomic Balkanization.â26×26. Id. (quoting Hughes v. Oklahoma, 441 U.S. 322, 325 (1979)). The Courtâs dormant commerce clause jurisprudence, Justice Alito wrote, stops states from âsubjecting interstate commerce to the burden of âmultiple taxation.ââ27×27. Id. (quoting Nw. States Portland Cement Co. v. Minnesota, 358 U.S. 450, 458 (1959)).
Turning to the case at hand, the Court explained that its precedents âall but dictate[d]â the conclusion that Marylandâs income tax scheme violated the dormant commerce clause.28×28. Id. Justice Alito highlighted three cases in which the Court held that state taxes levied against domiciliary corporations violated the dormant commerce clause.29×29. Id. at 1795. The cases were J.D. Adams Manufacturing Co. v. Storen, 304 U.S. 307 (1938); Gwin, White & Prince, Inc. v. Henneford, 305 U.S. 434 (1939); and Central Greyhound Lines, Inc. v. Mealey, 334 U.S. 653 (1948). In each of these cases, the Court invalidated taxes that risked doubly taxing out-of-state earnings and that discriminated against interstate activity.30×30. Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1795. Justice Alito swatted away the attempts of the principal dissent and Maryland to distinguish those cases. He rebutted their contention that those cases were distinguishable because they involved taxes of gross receipts rather than net income, noting that recent cases reject any formalistic difference between the two.31×31. Id. at 1795â96. He then attacked the claim that a meaningful distinction exists between taxes on corporations and taxes on natural persons32×32. Id. at 1796â97. : he argued that states provide costly benefits to both individuals and corporations33×33. Id. at 1797. and rejected the idea that the power of individuals to vote can justify differential treatment.34×34. In particular, Justice Alito dismissed the dissentâs claim that the ability to vote obviated the need to enforce the dormant commerce clause, remarking that âthe notion that the victims of such discrimination have a complete remedy at the polls is fancifulâ given that the doubly taxed individuals are likely to be a political minority. Id. at 1798. Justice Alito further opined that it was âeven more farfetchedâ to believe residents have more power to influence lawmakers than large corporations do. Id. Thus, the Court established that the dormant commerce clause places limits on a stateâs ability to tax its residentsâ income.35×35. The dissentâs contention that Maryland was free âto tax all of the income of its residents, wherever earned,â Justice Alito wrote, âconfuses what a State may do without violating the Due Process Clause . . . with what it may do without violating the Commerce Clause.â Id. While he acknowledged that states have the âraw powerâ to reach their residentsâ out-of-state income, Justice Alito explained that the jurisdictional power to tax has no bearing on the dormant commerce clause analysis. Id. at 1799.
The Court then applied the âinternal consistencyâ test to Marylandâs income tax scheme. Justice Alito explained that the internal consistency test works as follows: The Court imagines that every state has the same tax structure as the one at issue. If in that hypothetical scenario interstate commerce would be disadvantaged relative to intrastate commerce, the tax fails the internal consistency test and contravenes the dormant commerce clause.36×36. See id. at 1802. The Court used a simplified example to show that Marylandâs income tax scheme failed the test.37×37. See id. at 1803â04. The Court imagined that every state imposed taxes equivalent to Marylandâs county and special nonresident taxes. If April lived in State A and earned her income in State A, she would pay the county tax to State A. If Bob lived in State A but earned his income in State B he would pay both the county tax to State A and the special nonresident tax to State B. Because the internal logic of Marylandâs tax scheme thus âinherentlyâ subjected interstate income to higher taxes than it did intrastate income, it flunked the internal consistency test.38×38. Id. at 1804.
The tax schemeâs failure to pass the internal consistency test, the Court held, was sufficient to resolve the dormant commerce clause inquiry: Marylandâs income tax scheme was unconstitutional.39×39. Id. at 1805. Accordingly, the Court (unlike the Maryland high court) did not address whether the tax failed the external consistency test or Complete Autoâs discrimination prong. The Court defended this holding against the dissentsâ criticisms. It didnât matter, the Court explained, that internally consistent tax schemes could (in interaction with one another) produce the same sort of double taxation at issue in Wynne; the Constitution forbids not double taxation per se, but rather discrimination against interstate commerce.40×40. See id. at 1804. The Court also contested the dissentâs claim that its analysis ârequires a State taxing based on residence to ârecedeâ to a State taxing based on source.â41×41. Id. at 1805 (quoting id. at 1813 (Ginsburg, J., dissenting)). While Maryland could come into constitutional compliance by so ârecedingâ (that is, by offering credits for taxes paid to other states), the Court left open the possibility that Maryland could find another remedy for the unconstitutionality of its tax scheme.42×42. Id. at 1805â06. While refusing to comment on the constitutionality of alternative modes of compliance, the Court did state that â[b]y positing that Maryland could remedy the unconstitutionality of its tax scheme by eliminating the special nonresident tax, the principal dissent accepts that Marylandâs desire to tax based on residence need not ârecedeâ to another Stateâs desire to tax based on source.â Id. at 1806. The Court concluded by defending the dormant commerce clause against existential attacks waged in Justices Scaliaâs and Thomasâs dissents. See id. at 1806â07.
Justice Ginsburg authored the principal dissent.43×43. Justice Ginsburg was joined by Justices Scalia and Kagan. She began by invoking the often-acknowledged power of each state to âtax all the income of its residents, even income earned outside the taxing jurisdiction.â44×44. Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1813 (Ginsburg, J., dissenting) (quoting Okla. Tax Commân v. Chickasaw Nation, 515 U.S. 450, 462â63 (1995)). The rationales underpinning that power, she argued, are strong: not only do residents get lots of government services, but they also have political power that enables them to protect themselves against burdensome taxation.45×45. Id. at 1814â15. She also explained that each state has an âindependent interestâ in taxing nonresidents who work in-state and thereby benefit from the stateâs protection.46×46. Id. at 1816. And when it comes to establishing a tax regime, each state must prioritize between âcompeting tax policy objectivesâ â namely, each state must choose between (a) ensuring that those who receive similar government benefits pay similar taxes and (b) ensuring individuals are free from double taxation.47×47. Id. Justice Ginsburg argued that states âcannot achieve both objectives,â and contended that â[f]or at least a century, responsibility for striking the right balance between these two policy objectives has belonged to the States (and Congress), not this Court.â48×48. Id. After citing historical state income tax policies,49×49. Id. at 1816â17 (describing the early-twentieth-century personal income tax schemes in Wisconsin, Oklahoma, and Missouri). a number of due process cases, and two dormant commerce clause cases in support of the notion that a stateâs right to tax the income of its residents is limitless,50×50. Id. at 1817â19. Justice Ginsburg quoted Justice Holmesâs admonition that the long existence of systems of taxation is âa strong reason . . . for leaving any improvement that may be desired to the legislature.â51×51. Id. at 1819 (omission in original) (quoting Paddell v. City of New York, 211 U.S. 446, 448 (1908)).
Justice Ginsburg next claimed that failing the internal consistency test didnât spell certain death for Marylandâs income tax scheme. The Court, she argued, had previously allowed internally inconsistent taxes to stand.52×52. Id. at 1820â21 (first citing Shaffer v. Carter, 252 U.S. 37, 57 (1920); and then citing Am. Trucking Assâns, Inc. v. Mich. Pub. Serv. Commân, 545 U.S. 429, 438 (2005)). Whatâs more, she contended, the internal consistency test is no âcureâ for tax schemes that burden interstate commerce, since the interaction of divergent, internally consistent tax schemes can similarly burden interstate commerce.53×53. Id. at 1822 (quoting id. at 1806 (majority opinion)). Justice Ginsburg concluded by arguing that the âcompeting tax policy considerations this case implicatesâ are better left to state legislatures and Congress, bodies that âare constitutionally assigned and institutionally better equipped to balance such issues.â54×54. Id. at 1823.
Justices Scalia and Thomas also wrote dissenting opinions. Justice Scalia assailed the dormant commerce clause as a âjudicial fraudâ and a âbrazen inventionâ without textual basis in the Constitution,55×55. Id. at 1808 (Scalia, J., dissenting). and critiqued the doctrine as ad hoc, unstable, and incompatible with the judicial role.56×56. See id. at 1809â10. Justice Thomas (who would not apply the dormant commerce clause against any state law57×57. See id. at 1811 (Thomas, J., dissenting). ) claimed that founding-era states imposed income taxes that would have failed the Courtâs test, and argued that â[i]t seems highly implausible that those who ratified the Commerce Clause understood it to conflict with the income tax laws of their States and nonetheless adopted it without a word of concern.â58×58. Id. at 1812.
Although the Court invalidated Marylandâs income tax scheme after applying only the internal consistency test, Wynne could have important implications for the part of the âfair apportionmentâ test it didnât reach: the external consistency test, which requires states to apportion income so as to âreflect a reasonable sense of how income is generated.â59×59. Container Corp. of Am. v. Franchise Tax Bd., 463 U.S. 159, 169 (1983) (emphasis added). To put it another way, when Acmeâs activities in multiple states all play a part in generating its income, each state must apportion Acmeâs income so it taxes only the income actually generated by Acmeâs activities in that state. In its dicta disputing Justice Ginsburgâs claim that Wynne prioritizes a state taxing based on source over a state taxing based on residence, the majority seemed to accept that Maryland could fix its tax scheme by eliminating the special nonresident tax.60×60. See Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1805â06. But because that arrangement would still let Maryland levy its county tax on all of its residentsâ income generated out of state â apportioning no income whatsoever to those other states â it would seem to squarely violate the external consistency test. The majorityâs dicta thus suggest that the Court is not prepared to apply the external consistency test to statesâ personal income taxes, because the Court isnât equipped to decide what âfair apportionmentâ among states of earning and residence looks like in the personal income context.
When future courts hear dormant commerce clause challenges to personal income taxes, they may wonder how the Wynne Courtâs internal consistencyâcentric opinion bears upon the external consistency test.61×61. Professor Walter Hellerstein has noted that âexternal consistencyâ encompasses all of the content of the Courtâs historical fair apportionment jurisprudence. See Walter Hellerstein, State Taxation ¶ 4.16[2] (3d ed. 2015), Westlaw WGL-STATE. To maintain clarity, this comment refers to all fair apportionment requirements that donât fall within the internal consistency test as âexternal consistencyâ requirements. In previous cases scrutinizing state taxes under the dormant commerce clause, the Court has explained that taxes must pass both the internal consistency test and the external consistency test: failure of either test renders a tax unconstitutional.62×62. See, e.g., Container Corp., 463 U.S. at 169. And so, the Court followed its precedent in disposing with Wynne on internal consistency grounds. The Courtâs dicta, however, address issues relevant to the external consistency test, and seem to indicate that the Court could be inclined to treat the external consistency test differently when it comes to personal income taxes than it does when it comes to corporate income taxes.
The external consistency test, as applied in the corporate income context, mandates that a state reach no more of a taxpayerâs income than âthat portion of value that is fairly attributable to economic activity within the taxing State.â63×63. Okla. Tax Commân v. Jefferson Lines, Inc., 514 U.S. 175, 185 (1995); see also Daniel Shaviro, An Economic and Political Look at Federalism in Taxation, 90 Mich. L. Rev. 895, 917 (1992). The test is most vividly illustrated by cases involving interstate transportation. For example, the Court invalidated a New York tax on 100% of a resident bus companyâs receipts from routes on which 43% of the mileage took place in other states (and was thus earned under the âprotectionâ of other states).64×64. Cent. Greyhound Lines, Inc. v. Mealey, 334 U.S. 653, 662 (1948). The tax would have passed constitutional muster, the Court explained, had New York taxed only the portion of the travel that took place on New York roads. Id. at 663. The external consistency test doesnât apply only to such easily apportioned activity; it applies generally to statesâ taxes on multistate businesses.65×65. See, e.g., Container Corp., 463 U.S. at 169â70. When a corporation generates income in multiple states, each state may tax that corporation by multiplying the corporationâs total income by an âapportionment formulaâ in order to approximate the share of the total income generated by activity in the taxing state.66×66. Id. at 169. While this apportionment requirement doesnât eliminate a stateâs theoretical power to tax its corporate residentsâ income wherever earned, it does (at least in the corporate income context) establish a rule of priority in which a state of source gets preference over a state of residence when taxing income.67×67. Walter Hellerstein, State Taxation of Corporate Income from Intangibles: Allied-Signal and Beyond, 48 Tax L. Rev. 739, 812 n.398 (1993). This rule of priority largely limits the power of the state of residence to reach income it canât assert was generated under its protection.
If personal income taxes were to receive the exact same dormant commerce clause scrutiny as corporate income taxes, they would also have to pass the external consistency test. Indeed, the Maryland Court of Appeals, after determining that the personal income tax was subject to dormant commerce clause strictures, didnât hesitate before applying this test. The Maryland high court concluded that â[b]ecause no credit is given with respect to the county tax for income earned out-of-state,â Maryland impermissibly taxed residentsâ income âderived entirely from out-of-state sourcesâ and so failed the external consistency test.68×68. Md. State Comptroller of the Treasury v. Wynne, 64 A.3d 453, 467 (Md. 2013).
But, in contrast to the Maryland courtâs willingness to reach the external consistency test, Wynneâs dicta indicate the Court would be hesitant to apply the test to taxes on natural personsâ income. Most critically, the logic of the Courtâs claim that Wynne doesnât force states taxing based on residence to ârecedeâ to states taxing based on source seems to contradict the external consistency testâs requirements. The Court cast doubt on its allegiance to the external consistency test when it touted the dissentâs argument that âMaryland could remedy the unconstitutionality of its tax scheme by eliminating the special nonresident taxâ as evidence that Wynne establishes no rule of priority.69×69. Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1806. Thatâs because if Maryland eliminated the special nonresident tax, it would still be imposing a county tax on 100% of its residentsâ income, with no credit offered for income earned (and taxed) out of state. And while the Court was careful not to prematurely endorse the constitutionality of such an unapportioned tax, the Court did highlight the âflexibilityâ that states have in responding to the invalidation of their tax schemes.70×70. Id. at 1806 (quoting McKesson Corp. v. Div. of Alcoholic Beverages & Tobacco, 496 U.S. 18, 39 (1990)). The Court also suggested that the mere risk of multiple taxation of interstate activities was of little constitutional significance, id. at 1804, a claim that does not directly conflict with external consistency precedent, but is in some tension with the Courtâs previous pronouncement that âthe threat of real multiple taxation . . . may indicate a Stateâs impermissible overreaching,â Okla. Tax Commân v. Jefferson Lines, Inc., 514 U.S. 175, 185 (1995).
A tax scheme like the one that Wynneâs dicta suggested, however, would fail the external consistency test because it would make no attempt whatsoever to âslic[e] a taxable pie among several States in which the taxpayerâs activities contributed to taxable value.â71×71. Jefferson Lines, 514 U.S. at 186; see also Hellerstein, supra note 61, ¶ 20.10[2][b] (â[T]he Commerce Clause would limit the ability of a resident state to refuse to grant personal income tax credits for source based taxes imposed on income from . . . employment carried on in other states . . . .â). The only way a state of residence could comply with this requirement while simultaneously taxing income its residents earn out of state would be if the taxpayersâ activities in their states of residence contributed to all of their income (and their activities in the state of earning contributed nothing), a logically untenable position. While the simplest resolution of this conflict between precedent and dicta is to reject the dicta, the Courtâs language could indicate its willingness to abstain from imposing the external consistency test on personal income tax schemes. Such an abstention, if followed through with, would likely arise from the Courtâs sense that Congress is better situated to determine which basis of taxation â residence or source â deserves primacy.
Indeed, as a general matter, the Courtâs dormant commerce clause cases evince an understanding that prudence limits the application of the external consistency requirement to invalidate state taxes â an understanding premised largely on Congressâs power to remedy impermissibly discriminatory state taxation through legislation.72×72. See Hellerstein, supra note 61, ¶ 4.24[1]; see also id. ¶ 4.24[2]. For example, the Court relied upon a prudential rationale when it refused to mandate a nationally uniform corporate-income apportionment formula: while the Court conceded that a nationally uniform formula might be constitutionally necessary to avoid discriminatory interstate effects,73×73. See Moorman Mfg. Co. v. Bair, 437 U.S. 267, 280 (1978) (â[T]he freedom of the States to formulate independent policy in this area may have to yield to an overriding national interest in uniformity . . . .â). it nonetheless refused to dictate what that formula looked like because âthe Constitution has committed such policy decisionsâ to Congress.74×74. Id. The Court reaffirmed the political nature of the question of apportionment in a later case, explaining that Moorman stands for the proposition that âthat task [is] . . . essentially legislativeâ and so the Court âdeclined to undertake it.â Container Corp. of Am. v. Franchise Tax Bd., 463 U.S. 159, 171 (1983). Justice White also wrote in one case that he voted to sustain a state tax because Congressâs power to resolve potential issues âcounsel[ed] withholding [the Courtâs] hand.â Commonwealth Edison Co. v. Montana, 453 U.S. 609, 637 (1981) (White, J., concurring). Justices Frankfurter and Black also made competence pleas in state tax cases. See Hellerstein, supra note 61, ¶ 4.24[2]. And although the Court didnât concede that it lacked the competence to set any limits on the reasonableness of apportionment of corporate earnings,75×75. See Container Corp., 463 U.S. at 169â70 (implying just such competence). the Court did recognize that determining exactly how much of a corporationâs earnings was fairly attributable to the state where a corporation makes sales (as opposed to the state of corporate headquarters) was beyond the judicial ken.
When it comes to personal income taxes, the Court might believe itâs incompetent to establish a meaningful external consistency standard â and that any standard would be so toothless that either the state of residence or the state of source could validly apportion 100% of an individualâs income to itself. There are meaningful differences between the ways a taxpaying corporationâs state of residence and a taxpaying individualâs state of residence contribute to each taxpayerâs income: whereas a corporation can âresideâ in a state in which it has a minimal presence, an individual invariably receives a huge number of benefits from her state of residence.76×76. See Brief of the International Municipal Lawyers Assân & Other State & Local Government Groups as Amici Curiae in Support of Petitioner at 6â10, Wynne, 135 S. Ct. 1787 (No. 13-485); see also Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1816 (Ginsburg, J., dissenting). As a result, a state can more persuasively claim that its protections contribute to the income that its human residents earn out of state than it can with regard to income that its corporate residents earn via out-of-state sales.
In the face of this difference between individual and corporate income, the Court might not feel compelled to impose the external consistency requirement on individual income taxes.77×77. Such an approach would not be inconsistent with the Courtâs rejection of the argument that the different benefits flowing to individuals exempt individual income taxes from dormant commerce clause scrutiny; that rejection merely affirmed that individual income taxes cannot be discriminatory, not that they must be apportioned identically to corporate income taxes. See Wynne, 135 S. Ct. at 1797 (majority opinion). As Justice Ginsburg noted, any attempt by the Court to say which state gets priority claim to individualsâ income would have major implications for state tax policy, and Congress can fashion rules to resolve conflicts among state tax policies.78×78. See id. at 1816, 1823 (Ginsburg, J., dissenting). The Court might thus see fit to follow its dicta in recognition of the difficult questions that it would have to answer in order to impose a meaningful external consistency test on state income tax schemes â and the political ramifications that such imposition would entail.
Â